Bill Totten's Weblog

Monday, May 25, 2009

Germany's 1923 Hyperinflation

A "Private" Affair

by Stephen Zarlenga, researcher in monetary history and theory

The Barnes Review (July - August 1999)


Discussions of the dangers of inflation inevitably end up at the worst-ever case known - the German hyperinflation of 1923. Accompanied by economists' moralizing warnings of the dire results of governments' printing paper money, the German hyperinflation is used as a horror story by those who advocate a plutocratic control over money. However (as in other cases), when the monetary facts are actually examined, the argument falls apart as it becomes clear that the bankers themselves and speculators were the primary cause of the German hyperinflation, which was not stopped until the government took decisive action against them.

Lagging behind other European nations, Germany had no central government until the formation of the German Federation in 1815. The major "German" finance houses of the medieval period had been quick students of Italian finance methods at Venice's Foundacio De Tedeschi, and some, like the Fuggers of southern Germany, had grown to international prominence as factors in financing the election of emperors.

In 1900 the Deutsche Bank financed construction of the Turkey-Baghdad Railway. This meant German industry, already linked to Istanbul (the famous Orient Express line), could be directly linked to farther eastern markets, circumventing Britain's naval supremacy. Hjalmar Schacht, one of 20th-century Germany's key financial figures, noted that this railway disturbed England's rulers.

There are other reports of British concern over German dynamism. Francis Neilson, a former British member of Parliament and author of The Makers of War (1950), presented the viewpoint that England's "old boy network" didn't consider itself up to competing with Germany industrially.

In 1907 the widely respected American diplomat Henry White was instructed to ascertain British views. He met with his friend Arthur Balfour. White's daughter "overheard" one of White's conversations with Balfour as follows (it was probably White's way of not directly violating secrecy pledges):

Balfour: We are probably fools not to find a reason for declaring war on Germany before she builds too many ships and takes away our trade.

White: If you wish to compete with German trade, work harder.

Balfour: That would mean lowering our standard of living. Perhaps it would be simpler for us to have a war... Is it a question of right or wrong? Maybe it is just a question of keeping our supremacy. {1}


European heads of state were still largely hereditarily selected. Court intrigue and the system of secret treaties played a larger role than today, and lent itself to warmongering. According to Neilson, the British Parliament had not been informed that England was committed to a continental war to defend France, if necessary. {2}

Adding to the problem, the Schlieffen Plan for the emergency military mobilization of Germany did not have the foresight to allow time for diplomatic negotiations. Thus the assassination of Austrian Archduke Ferdinand in Sarajevo by anarchists was given the power of a trigger in starting World War One.

Alfred E Zimmern's rare thirteen-page monograph, The Economic Weapon {3}, written during World War One, deserves attention because of its content and its source. According to Professor Carroll Quigley [himself a notable member of the Establishment], Zimmern was a member of what he called the "Anglo-American Establishment". {4}

Zimmern sums up the situation on page 1:

What is the economic situation? It can be stated in one sentence: The Central Powers are being besieged by practically the entire world, and they have no means at their disposal for bringing the siege to an end.


Zimmern pointed out this was the first time in history that such a large "siege" had been attempted, and Germany didn't think it was possible. "In December 1915, the chancellor remarked: 'Does anyone seriously believe that we can lose the war on account of a shortage of rubber?' Germany's war preparations were made on an estimate 'of a war of one year's duration at the outside'."

Then Zimmern raised the veil on what was planned for Germany:

What will happen in the normal course when peace is signed?... [W]ill the cessation of the physical blockade of German harbors by itself involve the raising of the siege?... But without raw materials there can be no industrial employment; and demobilization without employment ready to hand for the disbanded soldier spells social disorder... The Allies ... by their command of essential supplies control the demobilization of the German army and therewith the whole process of German recuperation.

The whole civilized world will be faced... with the prospect of a shortage, if not a famine over a period calculated ... at no less than three years.


And: "Some will have to go short. Who more naturally than Germany? It is not as if the boycott had to be organized. It will come about almost of itself unless special provision is made in the peace."

But Lord Lothian (who Quigley lists as a fellow member with Zimmern of the Anglo-American Establishment), was the co-author of the Treaty of Versailles. {5} The treaty would provide for the opposite of a just peace.

The Treaty of Versailles turned out to be an instrument of continuing aggression. Even at the time, it drew strong condemnation. The American Secretary of State Robert Lansing wrote:

The impression made by it is one of disappointment, of regret, and of depression. The terms of the peace appear immeasurably harsh and humiliating, while many of them seem to me impossible of performance ... The League [of Nations] as now constituted will be the prey of greed and intrigue.


Lansing noted that:

On May 17, I received Mr Bullitt's letter of resignation and also letters from five of our principal experts protesting against the terms of peace and stating that they considered them as an abandonment of the principles Americans had fought for. {6}

Francisco Nitti, the prime minister of Italy, wrote:

It will remain forever a terrible precedent in modern history that, against all pledges, all precedents and all traditions, the representatives of Germany were never even heard, nothing was left to them but to sign a treaty at a moment when famine and exhaustion and threat of revolution made it impossible not to sign ... In the old canon law of the church it was laid down that everyone must have a hearing, even the devil ... the new society of nations did not even obey the precepts which the dark Middle Ages held sacred on behalf of the accused. {7}

The cost of the war of all participants totaled three times the value of all property in Germany. She was ordered to pay an impossible 1.7 billion marks a year (in foreign exchange) for 59 years, until 1988. Even worse, according to the normally circumspect banker, Hjalmar Schacht:: "The Treaty of Versailles is a model of ingenious measures for the economic destruction of Germany", adding:

Every natural economic advance, every step toward the restoration of economic confidence was made impossible by the influence of the foreign political factor. {8}


Further complicating matters, immediately after the surrender, on November 9 1918, the threatened leftist and communist coup was carried out, when the Revolutionary Council of Commissioners of the People overthrew the German government and temporarily took power.

England had financed twenty percent of World War One through taxation, France zero percent and Germany six percent. Schacht wrote that Germany's money supply rose from 7.2 billion marks in December 1914, up to 28.4 billion marks on November 7 1918; the end of the open warfare. This meant circulation went from 110 to 430 marks per person.

An index of wholesale prices had risen from 100 in 1913, to 234 in late 1918, performing close to British indexes. The effect on working people was cushioned as workmen's wages rose from 100 to 248 during the period. Thus World War One seriously damaged but didn't destroy Germany's monetary system. That came under the auspices of the occupying forces.

The great German hyperinflation of 1922 and 1923 is one of the most widely cited examples by those who insist that private bankers, not governments, should control the money system. What is practically unknown about that sordid affair is that it occurred under control of a privately owned and controlled central bank.

The Reichsbank had a form of private ownership, but with public control; the president and directors being officials of the German government, appointed by the emperor, for life. There was a sharing of the revenue of the central bank between the private shareholders and the government. Unfortunately, the League of Nations experts delegated to guide the economic recovery of Germany wanted a more free market orientation for the German central bank. {9}

Schacht relates how the Allies had insisted that the Reichsbank be made more independent from the government: "On May 26 1922, the law establishing the independence of the Reichsbank and withdrawing from the chancellor of the Reich any influence on the conduct of the bank's business was promulgated". {10} This granting of total private control over the German currency set the stage for the worst inflation of all time.

How does the value of a currency get destroyed? In a sentence, by issuing or creating tremendously excessive amounts of it. Not just too much of it, but way too much. This excessive issue can happen in different ways; for example, by British counterfeiting, as occurred with the US continental currency. The central bank itself might print too much currency; or the central bank might allow speculators to destroy a currency, through excessive short selling of it, similar to short selling a company's shares.

The destruction of a national currency through "speculation" is what concerns us in this case. It is also a timely topic considering how speculation was recently allowed to destroy several Asian currencies, which have dropped over fifty percent against the dollar, in a few months time, threatening the lives of millions.

It works like this. First, for whatever reason, there is some obvious weakness involved in the currency. In Germany's case it was World War One, and the need for foreign currency for reparations payments. In the case of the Asian countries, they had a need for dollars in order to repay foreign debts coming due.

Such problems can be solved over time and usually require some national contribution toward their solution, in the form of taxes, or temporary lowering of living standards. However, because currency speculation is still erroneously viewed as a legitimate activity, private speculators are allowed to make a weak situation immeasurably worse; to take billions of dollars in "profits" out of the situation, by selling short the currency in question. Not just selling currency which they owned, but making contracts to sell currency which they didn't own - to sell it short.

If done in large enough amounts, such short selling soon has self-fulfilling results, driving down the value of the currency, faster and further than it otherwise would have fallen. Then at some point, panic strikes, which causes widespread flight from the currency by those who actually hold it. It drops precipitously. The short selling speculators are then able to buy back the currency which they sold short, and obtain tremendous profits, at the expense of the industrialists and working people whose lives and enterprises were dependent on that currency.

The free market gang claim that it's all the fault of the government that the currency was weak in the first place. But by what logic does it follow that speculators take this money from those already in trouble? And they call this business? It should be viewed as a form of aggression, no less harmful than dropping bombs on the country in question. The recent outrage expressed on this by the prime minister of Malaysia got it right.

The proper reaction would be to help strengthen the currency, not promote its destruction. Industrialists should realize that when they allow such vicious activity to be included under the umbrella of "business activity", they are cutting their own throats. They should help isolate such sociopathic speculators, so that they can be stopped by the law.

Back to Germany. Far too many German marks were being created under the privately controlled Reichsbank. Exactly how, will be discussed shortly. These excessive issues drove down the value of the mark:

By July 1922, the German mark fell to 300 marks for $1; in November it was at 9,000 to $1; by January 1923 it was at 49,000 to $1; by July 1923, it was at 1,100,000 to $1. It reached 2.5 trillion marks to $1 in mid-November 1923, varying from city to city. {11}

In the monetary chaos, Hamburg, Bremen and Kiel established private banks to issue money backed by gold and foreign exchange. The private Reichsbank printing presses had been unable to keep up, and other private parties were given the authority to issue money. Schacht estimated that about half the money in circulation was private money from other than Reichsbank sources.

Hjalmar Schacht's 1967 book, The Magic of Money, presents what appears to be a contradictory explanation of the private Reichsbank's role in the inflation disaster.

First in the hackneyed tradition of economists, he is prepared to let the private Reichsbank off the hook very easily, and blame the government's difficult situation instead, and minimized the connection of the private control of the central bank with the inflation, as mere coincidence:

The Reichsbank upon which this responsibility (to control inflation) fell could not make up its mind to take action. It held the view that it was useless to attempt to stabilize the currency so long as the Ruhr was occupied and the war debts remained unfixed.

Schacht lamented:

[To an] ever-growing extent the Reich had to resort to the Reichsbank if it was to prolong its existence, and because the point at issue was the survival of the Reich, the Reichsbank did not regard itself justified in refusing, even after the passing, in 1922, of the law which gave it formal autonomy. The legislation of 1922, which was intended to free the Reichsbank from the claims of the state, came to grief at the decisive moment because the Reich could not find any way of holding its head above the water other than by the inflationary expedient of printing bank notes. {12}


In other words, they did it to save the government; assumedly making the new issues of Reichsmarks available for government expenditures.

After a few pages, Schacht gave the real explanation. Schacht was a lifelong member of the banking fraternity, reaching its highest levels. He may have felt compelled to give his banker peers and their PR corps something innocuous to quote. But Schacht also had a streak of German nationalism, and more than that, an almost sacred devotion to a stable mark. He had watched helplessly as the hyperinflation destroyed "his mark".

For whatever reasons, after 44 years he then proceeded to let the cat out of the bag, writing in German, with some truly remarkable admissions that shatter the "accepted wisdom" the financial community has promulgated on the German hyperinflation.

But first, some background to the events of 1923 is needed: As the hyperinflation wreaked destruction many plans were put forward to stabilize the currency. In 1923, a conservative monetary theorist, Karl Helfferich, advanced a plan of basing the currency on agricultural grains and putting its administration into the hands of a private bank run by agricultural interests. The support of the farming community was not sufficient to have this plan adopted.

Because the mark had been so badly ruined for eighteen months, it was felt that, psychologically, an altogether different currency was necessary. Plans centered on a new currency to be called the Rentenmark. The plan was simple: introduce the new currency, in a limited quantity and don't overissue it, so that the notes keep their value and thereby reestablish confidence.

In order to create a largely psychological separation from the Reichsbank, the Rentenbank was set up to loan Rentenmarks, to the Reichsbank; and the Reichsbank issued Rentenmark credits. The Rentenbank was not truly independent of the Reichsbank.

Schacht, with 23 years of banking experience, agreed to be made the government's commissioner of currency, a new position created to stabilize the currency. At the time, monetary theorists such as Helfferich were arguing that the state wasn't powerful enough to "create money which would command public confidence, and that only the business elements of the country acting of their own free will were competent to accomplish this task". {13} Schacht knew better.

This process took time, to convince the population that the new currency would not be over-issued:

"The invention of the Rentenmark did not stabilize the mark. The battle for stabilization continued for a year, passing through many a difficult phase", he wrote, asserting that it was not the Rentenmark but the subsequent credit restrictions on how many were created that stabilized the currency. {14}

The formal structure of the Reichsbank had apparently not been altered in this stabilization period; but it was clearly the government and society that now actively exercised the monetary control:

The concurrent political and economic difficulties of the Reich threatened rapidly to culminate in a catastrophe, when the government at length braced itself to the resolve to take into its hands once more the control of the [destiny] of the German people. In this policy the principal item was the endeavor to stabilize the mark. {15}

The Rentenmarks were put into circulation in three days, from November 15 1923. They were not legal tender; there was no fixed relation to the fallen Reichsmark; and the Rentenmarks could not be used for international payments.

Schacht stopped all other money issuers and sent all Reichsbank holdings of private money back to their source for immediate payment, despite great howls of pain from all these private moneyers; such as the Hugo Stinnes group.

The Rentenmarks were expressly forbidden to be transferred to foreigners. This meant that speculators could not trade them for foreign exchange to support their speculations when prices went against them. Schacht's initial actions thus crushed the speculators, a necessary first step in most monetary reform:

The speculators had learnt that the Reichsbank was now able, if it decided to do so, to put an end to all speculation on the foreign exchange market. The success of the campaign meant an immeasurable increase in the confidence of the public in the stabilization of the mark. {16}

How did Schacht determine the value of the Rentenmarks? By the seat of his pants. On November 20 1923, it was set at $1=4.2 trillion Rentenmarks. Fixing it there was convenient because in peacetime it had been $1 to 4.2 marks. He remarked that:

There was no mathematical formula which could provide the solution. It was a question of instinct, and ultimately of experiment; but the form of the experiment remained one and the same - namely, the contraction of the legal currency. {17}

It was in describing his 1924 battles in stabilizing the Rentenmarks that Schacht made his revelation; giving the real mechanism of the hyperinflation. Schacht was obviously very upset when the speculators continued to attack the new Rentenmark currency. By the end of November 1923:

The dollar reached an exchange rate of twelve trillion marks on the free market of the Cologne Bourse. This speculation was not only hostile to the country's economic interests, it was also stupid. In previous years such speculation had been carried on either with loans which the Reichsbank granted lavishly, or with emergency money which one printed oneself, and then exchanged for Reichsmarks. [Emphasis added.]


Now however, three things had happened. The emergency money had lost its value. It was no longer possible to exchange it for Reichsmarks. The loans formerly easily obtained from the Reichsbank were no longer granted, and the Rentenmark could not be used abroad. For these reasons the speculators were unable to pay for the dollars they had bought when payment became due (and they) made considerable losses. {18}

Thus Schacht is telling us that the speculation against the mark, the short selling of the mark, was financed by lavish loans from the private Reichsbank. The margin requirements which the anti-mark speculators needed, and without which they could not have attacked the mark, was provided by the private Reichsbank.

This contradicts Schacht's earlier explanation, for there is no way to interpret or justify "lavishly" loaning to anti-mark speculators as "helping to keep the government's head above the water". Just the opposite. Schacht was a bright fellow, and he wanted this point to be understood. He waited until he wrote The Magic of Money in 1967. His earlier book, The Stabilization of the Mark (1927), discussed inflation profiteering, but did not clearly identify the private Reichsbank itself as financing such speculation; making it so convenient to go short of the mark.

Thus we now realize that it was a privately owned and privately controlled central bank, which made loans to private speculators, to enable them to put up the necessary margin to speculate against the nation's currency. Such speculation helped create a one-way street, down, for the German mark. Soon a continuous panic set in, and not just speculators, but everyone else had to do what they could to get out of their marks, further fueling the disaster.

This factor has been largely unknown, and "the government" typically gets the blame for this mother of all inflations, in economic propagandizing.

Why did Schacht give these details after 44 years, when he could have easily "forgotten" about them? Probably because his sense of justice was deeply offended over the destruction of the mark by Germany's plutocracy - especially her bankers.

For hundreds of years Schacht's family lived in the Ditmarschen area, between the Elbe and Eider rivers. This is a land of free farmers, notably lacking the castles found in most parts of Germany. Schacht studied German philology, then did his doctorate on the English mercantilists, demonstrating how they were aware of the quantity aspect of money from the 1500s and 1600s. {19}

Finally, Hjalmar Horace Greeley Schacht was his full name; his father was a naturalized American citizen who had returned to Germany as a newspaper editor.

In December 1923, Schacht was made president of the Reichsbank. Before assuming office, he went to England for a meeting with Montagu Norman, governor of the Bank of England. Schacht wrote:

I have never engaged in academic controversy either with the nominalists or with the advocates of an index currency. I have invariably said frankly that I do not set great store by currency theories, but should be prepared at any moment to accept any currency adopted by America and England. {20}

Legitimate credit demands led to a rapid growth of credit extended by the Reichsbank and the Rentenbank from 609 million Rentenmarks at the end of 1923, to two billion at the end of March 1924. Sensing weakness, the speculators moved in for a kill, ignoring the law regarding foreign exchange purchases.

In March of 1924 Schacht's regulations (he calls them "instructions") were being violated by the banks:

"[W]hereby foreign exchange purchase orders were to be executed by the banks only if full cover in German currency was provided by the purchaser, this had not been heeded by various banking firms". These banks, including one of the largest, impudently ignored Reichsbank reminders, so their bills were denied re-discounting by the Reichsbank, effectively blocking them, and ending the violations.

From April 7 1924 the Reichsbank refused to issue new credits for two months. "The Reichsbank plumped for the stability of the mark", wrote Schacht. The speculators had to turn their foreign holdings over to pay their debts, as their trading positions against the Rentenmark lost money. In this way the Reichsbank increased its foreign exchange reserves from 600 million marks worth, at beginning of April 1924, to more than double that by August 7 1924. {21} This indicates a still immense amount of anti-mark speculation: "...[A]nd the country was still filled with numbers of such speculators, who were not in the least concerned as to whether their good name and reputation suffered so long as they could pocket the profits", wrote Schacht. {22}

The contraction pursued by Schacht was brutal. One-month money rates went from thirty percent to 45 percent. Overdraft charges rose from forty percent to eighty percent! After July 1924 they began falling. Schacht's restriction of money was so harsh that the German government-operated post office and railways formed their own banks and began building capital much faster than the private sector.

By the end of 1924, merchants and others were treating the Rentenmark and the old Reichsmark as equal, and Schacht converted the Rentenmarks into Reichsmarks. He had always been against the Rentenmarks, considering them a monetary error:

"I made every endeavor to take the Rentenmark out of circulation as quickly as possible. To this end the Reichsbank gave the Rentenmark parity with the new Reichsmark" and converted them into Reichsmarks.

In 1923 the League of Nations had invited General Charles Gates Dawes to chair a committee to deal with the controversial problem of German reparations payments. The Dawes Report recommended reducing the reparations from 132 billion marks to 37 billion marks. America would lend Germany money for reparations payments to France and England, which countries would then be able to pay some of their war debts. Dawes was a banker and owned the Central Republic Bank and Trust Company of Chicago. The Allies implemented the plan; Dawes shared the Nobel Peace Prize for 1925 with Austen Chamberlain and then became vice president of the United States from 1925 to 1929, under Calvin Coolidge. In 1932 Dawes became chairman of Hoover's depression-era Reconstruction Finance Corporation, but then Dawes's bank failed and became the largest loss of the Reconstruction Finance Corporation, costing the US taxpayers $90 million.

When the Dawes experts, in structuring a new Reichsbank law, wanted to lengthen from ten to fifty years the length of time between the German government's periodic renewal of the note issuing power of the Reichsbank, Schacht managed to convince them of the need for some government approval of Reichsbank leadership. The Dawes committee proposed a revenue sharing arrangement of roughly forty percent to the private bank's shareholders, and 55 percent to the government. But eventually it was agreed the shareholders got half the first fifty million marks profit, 25 percent of the second fifty million profit; and ten percent of profits thereafter.

Later in 1924 there was a Dawes Plan loan to the Reichsbank, after which foreign credits began to pour in. Foreign bankers had confidence in Schacht. He was against the loans, and insisted that any foreign borrowings only be to finance production, not luxury, or consumption. This policy, from 1924 to 1929, resulted in Germany establishing Europe's most modern factory system of the period.

In July 1925, laws were passed to go back and examine and adjust inflation transactions. Injured parties could receive up to 25 percent of the real value of property they had exchanged for the bad paper. Schacht would resign the Reichsbank presidency in 1930, in protest over some economic rulings of the Allies. He was later reappointed when the National Socialists came to power.

When the war ended, a destitute Adolf Hitler was given an assignment by German army intelligence: to watch a tiny political group called the German Workers Party. He attended a small meeting where the ideas of Gottfried Feder made a deep impression on him.

In Mein Kampf (1925, 1926) Hitler wrote:

When I listened to Gottfried Feder's first lecture on breaking down the thralldom of interest [in June 1919], I knew at once that here we had a theoretic truth which will be of immense importance for the future of the German nation. {23}

Feder's captivating ideas were about money. At the base of his monetary views was the idea that the state should create and control its money supply through a nationalized central bank rather than have it created by privately owned banks, to whom interest would have to be paid. From this view was derived the conclusion that finance had enslaved the population, by usurping the nation's control of money.

Feder's monetary theories could easily have originated from the work of German monetary theorists such as George Knapp, whose book The State Theory of Money (1905) is still one of the classics in the monetary area. Right on page one, Knapp nails it:

Money is a creature of the law. A theory of money must therefore deal with legal history.


Knapp describes the invention of fiat money in these terms: "the most important achievement of economic civilization". For Knapp, the determination of whether something was money or not was: "our test, that the money is accepted in payments made to the state [that is, government] offices". {24}

Near the end of that book, Knapp casually mentions how German monetary theorists of his day, and earlier, would study and discuss American monetary theories. Thus the ultimate source of Feder's viewpoint was probably the American Populist movement of the 1870s and the ideas that movement promoted to establish a permanent greenback system.

When the National Socialists came to power, Schacht was reappointed head of the Reichsbank, partly to reassure German big business and foreign bankers. Schacht ridiculed Feder's monetary views:

Nationalization of banks, abolition of bondage to interest payments and introduction of state Giro 'Feder' money, those were the high-sounding phrases of a pressure group which aimed at the overthrow of our money and banking system. To keep this nonsense in check, [I] called a bankers' council, which made suggestions for tighter supervision and control over the banks. These suggestions were codified in the law of 1934 ... In the course of several discussions, I succeeded in dissuading Hitler from putting into practice the most foolish and dangerous of the ideas on banking and currency harbored by his party colleagues. {25}


Konrad Heiden noted that:

Industry did not want to put economic life at the mercy of such men as Gregor Strasser or Gottfried Feder, who, marching at the head of small property owners incited to revolution, wanted to hurl a bomb at large-scale wealth. Feder announced that the coming Hitler government would create a new form of treasury bill, to be given as credits to innumerable small businessmen, enabling them to re-employ hundreds of thousands and millions of workers. Would this be inflation? Yes, said Walter Funk, one of the many experts who for the past year or two had advised Hitler - an experienced and well-known finance writer, collaborator of Hjalmar Schacht and, in Hitler's own eyes, a guarantee that big business would treat him as an equal ... Hitler decided to put an end to the public squabble by appointing Göring to [oversee the questions].

Feder's faction was then given the four-year plan, to keep them busy. {26}

Feder quickly lost the battle with Schacht and the German business establishment. Perhaps he was in over his head monetarily. He wrote of his monetary plan: "Intensive study is required to master the details of this problem ... a pamphlet on the subject will shortly appear, which will give our members a full explanation of this most important task ..." {27} But this was 1934, which means he hadn't clearly reduced the problem to written form since 1919, over fifteen years.

"When the time comes, we shall deal with these things in further detail ..." Feder wrote, but indeed his party was in power, and the time had come.

Feder was put out to pasture by the National Socialists, serving as an under secretary in the Ministry of Economic Affairs, later to be transferred to commissioner for land settlement and then completely sidetracked as a lecturer at the Technische Hochschule in Berlin. Hitler and the National Socialists came to power on January 30 1933. Germany's foreign exchange and gold reserves had dropped from 2.6 billion marks in late 1929, down to 409 million in late 1933 and to only 83 million in late 1934. {28} According to classical economic theory, Germany was broke and would have to borrow. But classical economic theory is not very accurate.


Notes:

1 Allan Nevins, Henry White, Thirty Years of American Diplomacy. New York: Harper Brothers, 1930, pages 257-58.

2 Francis Nielsen, The Makers of War, Appleton, Wisconsin: Nelson Publishing Co, 1950.

3 A E Zimmern, The Economic Weapon. New York: George Doran, 1913-17.

4 Professor Carroll Quigley, The Anglo-American Establishment. New York: Books in Focus, 1982.

5 Konrad Heiden, Der Fuehrer. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1944 (written 1934), pages 639-49.

6 Robert Lansing, The Peace Negotiations. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1921, pages 272-75.

7 Francisco Nitti, The Wreck of Europe. As quoted by Nielsen, op cit (Note 2), page 151.

8 Hjalmar Schacht, Stabilizing the Mark. London: George Allen & Unwin, 1927, pages 46-51.

9 ibid, pages 116-7.

10 ibid, page 50.

11 ibid, pages 50-51.

12 Hjalmar Schacht, The Magic of Money. London: Oldbourne, 1967. Translated by page Erskine; pages 65-6.

13 Schacht, op cit (Note 8), page 84.

14 Schacht, op cit (Note 12), page 68.

15 Schacht, op cit (Note 8), page 89.

16 ibid, page 112.

17ibid, page 102.

18 Schacht, op cit (Note 12), page 70.

19 Norbert Muhlen, Schacht - Hitler's Magician. New York: Alliance/Longmans Green Co, 1939. Translated by E W Dickes.

20 Schacht, op cit (Note 8), page 208.

21 Schacht, op cit (Note 12), page 72.

22 Schacht, op cit (Note 8), page 159.

23 As quoted in Hitler's Official Program by Gottfried Feder. London: George Allen & Unwin, 1934; New York: Howard Ferbig Press, 1971, page 56.

24 George Knapp, State Theory of Money. 1909. London: Macmillan, 1924, pages 92-95.

25 Schacht, op cit (Note 12), page 49.

26 Heiden, op cit (Note 5), page 480.

27 Feder, op cit (Note 23), pages 59, 92.

28 Stephen M Roberts, The House That Hitler Built. New York: Harper Brothers, 1938, pages 146-47.


_____

The Barnes Review, 645 Pennsylvania Ave Southeast, Suite 100, Washington DC 20003, USA.

Published here with kind permission from TBR.

This digitalized version (c) 2003 by The Scriptorium.

http://www.wintersonnenwende.com/scriptorium/english/archives/articles/hyperinflation-e.html


Bill Totten http://www.ashisuto.co.jp/english/index.html

2 Comments:

  • The following comments address Gary North's article entitled "False Flag Infiltrators: Gold-Hating Fiat Money Inflationists Inside the Libertarian-Conservative Movement" at http://www.garynorth.com/public/4993.cfm .


    I was really surprised and dismayed to see this Libertarian rant posted on A-List, a supposedly Marxist list.

    The basic Libertarian position on money is that they want it backed 100% by gold because they distrust government. Note the words in the title, "Gold-Hating". The Libertarians hate government. I think anyone who hates or distrusts government must explain (1) why s/he distrusts the ability of democratic citizens to elect governments they can trust and (2) what s/he proposes as a replacement for democracy.

    The Founding Fathers of the United States emphasized that democracy isn't easy, that citizens must monitor their government with eternal vigilance. Perhaps the citizens of United States have grown too selfish, or too addicted to entertaining themselves or being entertained, to make democracy work. But the people who do not trust government should address THAT problem instead of bashing those like Ellen Brown, Stephen Zarlenga, Aristotle, Irving Fisher, the founders of the Chicago School of economics, (and me), who advocate fiat money.

    The main problem with the Gold Standard advocated by the Austrian School of economics and most Libertarians (the sources recommended by Gary North), is that gold is too limited in quantity to keep up with the economic growth we pursue. Thus if money must be backed by gold, two bad things are sure to happen:

    1. With not enough money to keep up with the growth we pursue, we will get deflation - that is, underemployment, poverty and accompaning miseries.

    2. Those who control or can supply the gold will dominate or have undue influence on the world's economies, much like those who control or can supply fossil fuels do today.

    As Aristotle pointed out, money is a social instrument and the only question is whether or not people accept it. The people of any nation will accept that nation's "fiat money" if (1) the government insists that taxes be paid in that fiat money (and is able collect most taxes due to it) and (2) the government makes all of its payments in that fiat money.

    CONTINUED IN NEXT COMMENT

    By Blogger Bill Totten, at 11:56 PM, May 26, 2009  

  • CONTINUED FROM PREVIOUS COMMENT

    What Ellen Brown, Stephen Zarlenga, Irving Fisher, The Chicago School of economics, many others, (and I) oppose is allowing private banks to create most of our money out of thin air (by making so-called "loans") and collecting interest on that money, instead of the government creating all of our money and spending it into circulation. If someone "loans" something to someone else, s/he cannot use it until it is returned. So if banks really were "loaning" money, the money "loaned" to one party would reduce the buying power of some other party by the amount "loaned". But when banks "loan" money they create it out of thin air, thereby increasing the money supply by the amount of the "loan" without reducing anyone else's buying power.

    Most governments allow private banks to "loan" at least ten times more money than those banks have in hand (in deposits and paid-in capital). Can you imagine airlines being allowed to sell ten times more seats than they have, hotels to rent ten times more rooms than they have, or rental car agencies to rent ten times more cars than they have? Why should only banks have such privilege?

    If all of us would demand our banks to give us actual cash (coins and bills) for all of the amounts in our bank accounts, the banks could supply less than ten percent of our demands. Thus, more than ninety percent of our currency is counterfeit; it has been counterfeited by private banks with our governments' permission.

    Moreover, most public debt comes from governments borrowing this money counterfeited by private banks instead of governments creating that money itself and spending it into circulation. For example, Japan's public debt is sixty percent greater than its annual GDP, and eighty percent of that public debt has been incurred to "service" the public debt (mostly to pay interest on that public debt); only twenty percent has been spent to benefit the Japanese nation or its citizens. Our (Japanese) government annually borrows about ninety percent of the money annually created by private banks and uses 75% of that borrowed money to "service" the public debt (mostly to pay interest on that public debt). The amount of money our government collects from income taxes is about the same as the amount it spends servicing the public debt.

    When I came to Japan forty years ago, Japan had no (zero) public debt. If our government had created the same amount of money that it has allowed private banks to create since I came to Japan, and spent that money into circulation, Japan would now have a public SURPLUS equal to its current public debt. Or it could have reduced by SIXTY PERCENT the amount of taxes collected over the past forty years and have zero public debt or surplus.

    The same holds for most other nations.

    Moreover, the reason most nations are addicted to economic growth is that ninety percent or more of their money is created by private banks as "loans" bearing interest. If the economy doesn't grow by the average rate of interest on those loans, either the banks or their borrowers go broke. Money created by government requires no interest, thus demands no growth to repay interest.

    I have other complaints about this article by Gary North, such as the insinuation that since Hitler did some truly horrible things, EVERYTHING he did was bad. Is that Gary North's interpretation of what Jesus Christ tried to teach us? But it's my bedtime, so I'll stop here.

    Bill Totten

    By Blogger Bill Totten, at 11:58 PM, May 26, 2009  

Post a Comment

<< Home